63
submitted 8 months ago* (last edited 8 months ago) by [email protected] to c/[email protected]

We are reading Volumes 1, 2, and 3 in one year. This will repeat yearly until communism is achieved. (Volume IV, often published under the title Theories of Surplus Value, will not be included, but comrades are welcome to set up other bookclubs.) This works out to about 6½ pages a day for a year, 46 pages a week.

I'll post the readings at the start of each week and @mention anybody interested.

Week 1, Jan 1-7, we are reading Volume 1, Chapter 1 'The Commodity'

Discuss the week's reading in the comments.

Use any translation/edition you like. Marxists.org has the Moore and Aveling translation in various file formats including epub and PDF: https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/

Ben Fowkes translation, PDF: http://libgen.is/book/index.php?md5=9C4A100BD61BB2DB9BE26773E4DBC5D

AernaLingus says: I noticed that the linked copy of the Fowkes translation doesn't have bookmarks, so I took the liberty of adding them myself. You can either download my version with the bookmarks added, or if you're a bit paranoid (can't blame ya) and don't mind some light command line work you can use the same simple script that I did with my formatted plaintext bookmarks to take the PDF from libgen and add the bookmarks yourself.


Resources

(These are not expected reading, these are here to help you if you so choose)


@[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected] @[email protected]

top 50 comments
sorted by: hot top controversial new old
[-] [email protected] 18 points 8 months ago

Uhhh... Let me be 30 yards of linen obama-drone

[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago

I'll be 30 yards of Lenin.

load more comments (1 replies)
[-] [email protected] 17 points 8 months ago* (last edited 8 months ago)

Just a word of encouragement to anyone struggling with chapter 1, the first three chapters (and chapter 1 especially) of Capital are notoriously heavy and hard to read. Marx and Engles both apologised for them! It’s not just you, you’re not lacking some quality, everyone finds the first 3 chapters tough. So don’t worry, go steady, get through them, especially if it’s your first Marxist reading. These chapters will make more sense retrospectively once you’ve seen how his arguments develop through the book(s). Some people (not me) even recommend reading the book out of order to get more from these chapters later on.

[-] [email protected] 11 points 8 months ago

This is what I am trying to keep in mind. This is also a reason why I don't really have much to say on it this week yet. I feel like thoughts are just starting to form. The parts about money for example are very thought provoking and have lead to some side-reading as well, but I can't form any coherent thoughts from them just yet.

I am trying to take this as a sort of primer and trust the process, very much appreciate the comments here as they help in forming thoughts about it a lot.

[-] [email protected] 10 points 8 months ago* (last edited 8 months ago)

Chapter 1 Section 3 kicked my ass lol

[-] [email protected] 17 points 8 months ago

Something I always come back to is how unbelievably obvious it becomes that most critics of Marx have never even opened Capital. Just the first like 10 paragraphs are so immediately enlightening to a different way to consider commodities than marginal value and pure exchange value.

I'm just gonna put all my thoughts in comments under this I guess. At least until more discussion arises

load more comments (7 replies)
[-] [email protected] 16 points 8 months ago

Decided to go with a new thread per chapter. One big huge thread would have been messy.

load more comments (5 replies)
[-] [email protected] 13 points 8 months ago* (last edited 8 months ago)

I read section 2 and like couldn't make much sense of it that It feels like I forgot everything in section 2, like I didn't read it at all, and it feels very embarrassing. I know I'm gonna have to reread it just like, got very abstract? At least for section 1 there are things that I could latch onto that like brings it all together? if that makes sense.

also in section 1, I really liked that Marx brought up diamonds in one of his examples since like that very relevant today, mainly with like artificial diamonds

load more comments (4 replies)
[-] [email protected] 13 points 8 months ago* (last edited 8 months ago)

Roast of the Week™ — Chapter One Edition

^brought^ ^to^ ^you^ ^by^ ^Starbucks^


"Truly comical is M. Bastiat, who imagines that the ancient Greeks and Romans lived by plunder alone. But when people plunder for centuries, there must always be something at hand for them to seize; the objects of plunder must be continually reproduced. It would thus appear that even Greeks and Romans had some process of production, consequently, an economy, which just as much constituted the material basis of their world, as bourgeois economy constitutes that of our modern world. Or perhaps Bastiat means, that a mode of production based on slavery is based on a system of plunder. In that case he treads on dangerous ground. If a giant thinker like Aristotle erred in his appreciation of slave labour, why should a dwarf economist like Bastiat be right in his appreciation of wage labour?" — Karl Marx, Capital vol 1, ch 1, footnote 34


:dwarf-economist:

large-adult-son

load more comments (1 replies)
[-] [email protected] 13 points 8 months ago

Fun game! How many common "refutations" of Marxism, the kind you might find in r/neoliberal, are directly addressed in the first chapter, especially in the first few pages of Capital.

[-] [email protected] 10 points 8 months ago

Refutations of the labor theory of value often start with a claim that LTV means that if a laborer slacks off and is super inefficient in their production, that this will somehow make the commodity they produce more valuable. Another version of this argument is the claim that LTV means that the quality of the commodity doesn't affect it's value, or that literally useless commodities are supposed to have value.

If these people have read Capital, they didn't get past the first 3 paragraphs, because paragraph 4 is where the discussion of use value begins. It turns out, surprise, commodities actually have to be useful to people and of usable quality to have value, they don't just magically gain value because someone spent a lot of labor on processing or manufacturing it. A few paragraphs later, we get to discussions about the average labor power of society, and how that correlates to prices of exchange. I think what people get backwards about LVT is that, yes, inefficient productivity CAN cause a commodity to be very valuable and have a high price, but only when the average amount of labor required to produce or extract it is very high.

Marx's example of diamond extraction is prescient: diamonds were legitimately quite difficult to extract from the earth in that era, and so their value was high. In our modern age, automation in mining and synthetic diamond production have dramatically increased the productivity of labor of diamond mining, which has made them much less valuable. That's not because any particular worker was working super slowly and inefficiently, nor is it because of the use value of diamonds decreased (their use value has arguably increased, as they've found applications in industrial processes).

(I think it's not until vol 3 that Marx talks about monopolies, but that's an obvious elephant in the room when talking about diamonds)

[-] [email protected] 8 points 8 months ago* (last edited 8 months ago)

Omg that link is so incredibly econ brained. It's like bourg academic economists have to write garbage like this to prove they haven't read Marx.

Marx's formulation of LTV is explicitly that what is contained in value isn't labor, it is labor power. It isn't just work, it is working for the capitalist. Power is energy exerted over time, allowing us to determine the actual material composition of value which eludes the bourgeois economist and their idealistic and transparently useless equilibrium pricing. Marx teaches while bourg economics obfuscates. He is explicit and repetitive, which makes us truly consider the "stuff" of value. This is why liberals can't tell the difference between mercantilism and capitalism. Value is our time and energy, our limited renewable life taken out of us, much of which is unpaid, and converted into commodities which converts to profits for the capitalist. Private property has never been anything but a grift, a way to trick the masses into voluntarily surrendering our material bodies for a dream sold to us by parasites.

Capitalism is class oppression, if it wasn't it wouldn't create value, it would just shift it around like medieval mercantilism. Honestly I think this is where a lot of progressive liberal "Marxists" end up in an overly economistic interpretation, especially class reductionist tendencies. Misreadings of Marx lead to bourgeois economic obfuscation; a close reading of Capital gives us the basic formulations for dispensing with bourgeois economics for good.

load more comments (1 replies)
[-] [email protected] 10 points 8 months ago

Just FYI, you gotta make a comment with all the @ names to ping your list of users to your post.

[-] [email protected] 10 points 8 months ago* (last edited 8 months ago)

Chapter 1 has been quite the trip. Difficult but very interesting and rewarding to grapple with. The commodity fetishism chapter is quite the finish.

mao-clap

P. S. It would be nice if the site mods stickied this on the front page to make it easier to find and drive more traffic to it.

load more comments (1 replies)
[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago

I just want to swing in to say I've read the chapter. Honestly, I thought I'd have picked up most of this stuff through cultural osmosis, but the first chapter here has already got me thinking about my employment in a more profound way than I was anticipating. Especially the part about productive power.

load more comments (2 replies)
[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago

I finished part 1 and 2 of chapter 1 today. Thanks to the posters in the other thread. Helped me get my head around some key terms, like value, concrete and abstract abor, and importantly the dual character of labor and its implications which had eluded me before. This is my second reading, but like with any book like this, I retained little the first time around.

I put it down after getting to part 3 as I found it either much harder, it seems like it was written in a more obscure way than the first two. Will get back to it tomorrow.

Hoping to post some notes and questions before the end of the week.

I don't know if anyone else feels like way, but the first chapter so far is so strange compared to other books I've read more recently on political economy, etc., because it starts with the most embryonic forms and works outward.

I read the relevant parts of Harvey's companion afterwards and it was okay. Good to confirm my understanding, but there were some oddities like taking about Marx not following Hegel's "synthesis" and then the next sentence explaining Marxs dialectical method which was pretty much a more accurate version of what Hegel actually does. And he doesn't make as concrete how the Dual Character of Labour is important (Marx does this better) and differs from previous works in political economy.

A reminder to everyone reading. Read the footnotes, sometimes the criticism of previous economists like Smith are written in very clear terms which show what Marx is building from and at times subverting. Also they can be pretty funny.

Looking forward to reading this with all of you!

[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago

I would avoid Harvey altogether.

load more comments (8 replies)
load more comments (1 replies)
[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago

I am hung up on the difference between the labor theory of value and “supply and demand” from school.

In Marx’s example of the corn out of season I understand the labor value is higher, but how is this different from saying less supply yields higher price?

Likewise with the loom example, the powered loom devalues the labor value but it could also be understood as an increase in supply per unit labor.

Is it the same concept framed differently or am I missing something?

[-] [email protected] 10 points 8 months ago

So, both the labor theory of value and "supply and demand" can both coexist in Marx's framework. They are compatible ideas. On the most basic level, cloth from a loom has a "use value." I can take the cloth and use it as a towel or a wash-cloth. Or, I can take the cloth, cut it up, and sew it together into a shirt, pants, etc. This "use value" is what basically determines the "demand" part of supply and demand. The "supply" part of supply and demand is basically determined by the labor that goes into making a thing. Someone has to plant the cotton, pick it, put it on the loom, dye it, transport it, sell it at the market, etc.

So, the higher a "use value" is, the higher the demand can be. And the more labor that has to go into making something, the lower the "supply" will be. This is a big, big oversimplification, of course. But to continue the cloth example, if you look at high-quality, durable blue jeans vs. a simple washcloth, the blue jeans have more "use value" to you as a consumer, so they can have a higher demand, increasing their price. You can then take the basic "use value" of the blue jeans and find its "exchange value" by looking at all sort of different things, including advertising, artificial scarcity, etc., which affect demand, and things like labor laws, monopolization, transportation infrastructure, etc. which affect supply.

The main difference between "exchange value" and price is that "exchange value" is independent of many complicating factors affecting price, like currency exchange rates, geographical differences in standard of living, etc. For example, the same blue jeans, with the exact same "use value" and "exchange value," might be sold at a higher price in New York City than Boise, Idaho, because people there are willing to pay more money for the same jeans. In a more online example, the exact same video game is sold at wildly different prices in different countries with different currencies. Discounts and sales affect prices even more drastically. But the existence of a coupon/discount does not change the "use value" of a game, or even its abstract "exchange value," just the price you pay for it.

This is actually a very subtle issue, with a lot of complicated details to work through. Here an entry about it from the literal "Encyclopedia of Marxism:"

Exchange-value differs from “price” in two ways: firstly, price is the actualisation of exchange-value, differing from one exchange to the next in response to a myriad of factors affecting the activity of exchange; secondly, price is the specific value-form, measuring the value of the commodity against money.

https://www.marxists.org/glossary/terms/e/x.htm#:~:text=Exchange%2Dvalue%20differs%20from%20%E2%80%9Cprice,of%20the%20commodity%20against%20money.

But to sum it up, Marx does believe in "supply and demand," which is perfectly compatible with the labor theory of value. It's just that labor determines the "supply" side of supply and demand. Because it is laborers who are ultimately "supplying" the raw materials, and the labor that goes into turning those raw materials into usable commodities. Hope this helps!

load more comments (5 replies)
load more comments (2 replies)
[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago* (last edited 8 months ago)

marx "A sugar-loaf being a body, is heavy, and therefore has weight: but we can neither see nor touch this weight. We can then take various pieces of iron, whose weight has been determined beforehand. The iron, as iron, is no more the form of manifestation of weight, than is the sugar-loaf. Nevertheless, in order to express the sugar-loaf as so much weight, we put it into a weight-relation with the iron. In this relation, the iron officiates as a body representing nothing but weight. A certain quantity of iron therefore serves as the measure of the sugar, and represents, in relation to the sugar-loaf, weight embodied, the form of manifestation of weight. This part is played by iron only within this relation, into which the sugar or any other body, whose weight has to be determined, enters with the iron. Were they not both heavy, they could not enter into this relation, and the one could therefore not serve as the expression of the weight of the other. When we throw both into the scales, we see in reality, that as weight they are the same, and that, therefore, when taken in proper proportions, they have the same weight."

limmy-what "bu' iron's hééviuh than sugar..."

[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago

Parts of this chapter are easier to understand if you imagine yourself in a commodity-money society. For example –

"a relation between two commodities such that the one commodity, whose own value is supposed to be expressed, counts directly only as a use-value, whereas the other commodity, in which that value is to be expressed, counts directly only as an exchange-value."

Imagine you live in a commodity-money society where everything is bought in beans. Presumably it's called Beanland or Beantopia. If I want to buy a television, I am only interested in its use-value; I hand over a certain amount of beans for the tv, and I'm only interested in beans for their exchange-value, not their usefulness as beans in generating farts.

"Since a commodity cannot be related to itself as equivalent, and therefore cannot make its own physical shape into the expression of its own value, it must be related to another commodity as equivalent, and therefore must make the physical shape of another commodity into its own value-form."

Beans are the physical form value takes. A television has its own value. Say its value is 5kg of beans. Then the beans are the "physical shape" that are the "expression" of the value of the tv.

'Relative form' and 'equivalent form'

The discussion of 'relative form' and 'equivalent form' is just saying that when you say 'x units of commodity A is as valuable as z units of commodity B', you conceptualise commodity A in a certain way (which he calls the relative form) and commodity B in the equivalent form. In Beantopia, beans are usually in the equivalent form. The equivalent form is when we use a commodity as a measuring-stick.

load more comments (9 replies)
[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago

I noticed that the linked copy of the Fowkes translation doesn't have bookmarks, so I took the liberty of adding them myself. You can either download my version with the bookmarks added, or if you're a bit paranoid (can't blame ya) and don't mind some light command line work you can use the same simple script that I did with my formatted plaintext bookmarks to take the PDF from libgen and add the bookmarks yourself.

If the download expires or you notice any errors with the bookmarks please let me know and I'll take care of it!

[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago

Hey, can you add me to the tag list? Thanks for organizing this

load more comments (1 replies)
[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago* (last edited 8 months ago)

Notes – Chapter 1

Not comprehensive or a replacement for reading. My personal highlights and emphases based on my thoughts while reading.

I will add section summaries as replies to this comment. Edit: okay this was a lot more work than I expected, let me know if you want more, otherwise I'm probably gonna stop

[-] [email protected] 10 points 8 months ago* (last edited 8 months ago)

Section 1: The Two Factors of a Commodity: Use-Value and Value

There are two essential components of the commodity, value and use-value.

  1. Use-value is the concrete, natural form of the commodity; its physical or measurable characteristics. Quality and quantity are determined by direct physical observation.
  2. Value is the abstract, social form of the commodity. Its quality or substance is homogeneous, abstract human labor. Its quantity is socially necessary labor time (SNLT).

We infer value through exchange value, the relationship between two commodities such as "one shirt is worth two hats."

Mass and weight provide an almost 1-to-1 analogy to value and exchange value, respectively. Objects have mass, but we do not measure absolute mass. We always measure relative mass by comparing the mass of two objects. One of these objects might be a standard kilogram weight. So weight expresses mass, it allows us access to it, but only through relative measurements of different massive objects. When weighing a mass, all other properties besides mass are ignored; color, volume, texture, etc. do not affect the weight. All other qualities except mass are "abstracted" away, and the objects are considered only insofar as they are masses.

Like the above, exchange value expresses value, but only after abstracting away all the distinct characteristics (use value) of the commodities. When we abstract from the use-value of a commodity, we also abstract from the concrete kind of the labor that produced it. This leaves a "residue" of abstract labor, human labor as such. This is the substance that forms value, common to all commodities.

Exchange value tells us about equivalence in terms of both quantity and quality. It is only logical to compare two quantities if they are of like quality. Think of it like converting to the right "units" to add two lengths: You can't directly add 5 inches + 3 centimeters, so you convert one into the units of the other in order to add them as quantities of the same substance.

[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago

Section 2: The two-fold Character of the Labour Embodied in Commodities

When we abstract from the use-value of a commodity, we also abstract from the concrete kind of the labor that produced it. This leaves a "residue" of abstract labor, human labor as such. This is the substance that forms value, common to all commodities.

This is a small point, but this dichotomy between concrete/natural, abstract/social continues throughout Capital in various forms.

Marx's method is not like the modern scientific method in which one test an arbitrary hypothesis. Here, the hypothesis (or thesis, more properly) is identified by the internal logic of the object of analysis (here, the commodity). This immanent critique is one example of Hegel's influence on Marx. The reason this is important: Chapter 1 is not a hypothetical or a final model to accept or deny (like a marginal utility theory, e.g.). It is a set of observations first and foremost, with logical inferences in tow.

load more comments (7 replies)
[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago

could someone help me understand what is meant by the 'dual character of labour'?

[-] [email protected] 8 points 8 months ago

The big term that he's getting at there is 'social labor' which is the form of labor that occurs within capitalist production (and socialist production).

Individual labor creates, as quarrk pointed out, use value. Something that is produced to be immediately consumed. Social labor produces exchange value, something that is means not to be immediately used, but to be exchanged for something else.

The thing with exchange value is that under capitalist production, the capitalist controls the exchange and the laborers only receive a portion of the exchange value they produce. So this 'dual character' of labor ends up feeding into the primary contradiction of capitalism which is wage labor.

[-] [email protected] 8 points 8 months ago

The appendix on the value form might be helpful.

”The analysis of the commodity has shown that it is something twofold, use-value and value. Hence in order for a thing to possess commodity-form, it must possess a twofold form, the form of a use-value and the form of value. The form of use-value is the form of the commodity’s body itself, iron, linen, etc., its tangible, sensible form of existence. This is the natural form (Naturalform) of the commodity. As opposed to this the value-form (Wertform) of the commodity is its social form.”

If commodities have a two-fold form, then there is correspondingly a two-fold form of the labor that produces them.

Just as commodities are viewed abstractly (via real exchange relations) as uniform value, abstracted from use-value, so also is the labor that produces value seen as a homogeneous human labor, abstracted from the particular trade or type of labor. Likewise, the type of labor that produces use-values or particular types of commodities, is itself a concrete labor of a definite kind like cotton spinning, baking, metalworking, etc.

Concrete labor produces concrete use values.

Abstract labor produces value.

[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago* (last edited 8 months ago)

Reviewing some passages I highlighted:

I am amused how Marx dispenses with typical Libertarian rebuttals to the Labor Theory of Value 150 years in advance.

E.g.

It might seem that if the value of a commodity is determined by the quantity of labour expended to produce it, it would be the more valuable the more unskilful and lazy the worker who produced it, because he would need more time to complete the article. However, the labour that forms the substance of value is equal human labour, the expenditure of identical human labour-power.

also

Finally, nothing can be a value without being an object of utility. If the thing is useless, so is the labour contained in it; the labour does not count as labour, and therefore creates no value.

I also had some fun noticing themes that I am generally aware of through osmosis, like the application of dialectical thought very early on

E.g.

The relative form of value and the equivalent form are two inseparable moments, which belong to and mutually condition each other; but at the same time, they are mutually exclusive or opposed extremes, i.e. poles of the expression of value.

Speaking of things happening very early on, Marx hints at a theme I expect we will be seeing in more detail down the road:

Labour, then, as the creator of use-values, as useful labour, is a condition of human existence which is independent of all forms of society; it is an external natural necessity which mediates the metabolism between man and nature, and therefore human life itself.

I suppose we are all generally familiar with the 'stagist' conception of economic development. While Marx hasn't gotten into any of that yet, I read this as foreshadowing that this labor theory of value will transcend all modes of production. That it isn't fundamentally changed whether a society is Feudal, Capitalist, or Communist. As he begins to hint at later in the chapter, it is the emergence of commodity relations and a society mediated through them which defines the Capitalist epoch, not the characteristics of value in and of itself.

Around this time I got too lazy to keep underlining interesting passages. The last one I underlined was this:

Finally, a particular kind of commodity acquires the form of the universal equivalent, because all other commodities make it the material embodiment of their uniform and universal form of value.

I read this and was like thinking-about-it

Then I flipped the page and it was like Bam! The Money Form!

[-] [email protected] 9 points 8 months ago

While Marx hasn't gotten into any of that yet, I read this as foreshadowing that this labor theory of value will transcend all modes of production. That it isn't fundamentally changed whether a society is Feudal, Capitalist, or Communist.

No, the labour theory of value is only a thing in a society wherein the capitalist mode of production prevails. A communist society would be dealing with pure use-values while in a feudal society (not in the market-interstices) the focus was also use-values, not on value or its reflection exchange-value.

The quote you are commenting on specifically notes that the universal form of labour, independent of social development, is labour as creator of use-values. This labour is a constant for human society, whereas labour as a producer of value is specific to a world where the commodity-form is generalized.

The labour theory of value also doesn't acknowledge all work as labour, e.g. the persistent denial even to this day by many that housework, childcare, etc, is labour.

Marx seems to be of two minds on the LToV in Capital; sometimes he seems to actually genuinely believe that there is something fundamentally unique about human labour or that reproduction of labour-powers can be excluded from his analysis because family is a natural sphere, and sometimes he seems to be simply accepting the bourgeois definition of 'real' labour as a given for purposes of criticising it on its own terms and sees the concept of commodity-value as a purely social thing with "not an atom of matter".

load more comments (5 replies)
load more comments (1 replies)
[-] [email protected] 8 points 8 months ago
load more comments (2 replies)
[-] [email protected] 8 points 8 months ago

As this first week draws to a close, I wanted to give a big thanks to @[email protected] for organizing and for their occasional inputs and clarifications! It's been great learning with other Hexbears reading it, perhaps for the first time, and seeing the epiphanies happen.

Sorry if anyone felt like I was over explaining or being overzealous in my replies. It is sometimes hard to share content you enjoy without being extremely intense lol

[-] [email protected] 8 points 8 months ago

hey, add me to the list, i finally got myself logged in after the latest hexbear update (had to delete 72MB in hexbear.net cookies).

load more comments (1 replies)
[-] [email protected] 7 points 8 months ago

alright add me to that tag list, gonna finally get through it

load more comments (2 replies)
load more comments
view more: next ›
this post was submitted on 01 Jan 2024
63 points (100.0% liked)

theory

409 readers
19 users here now

A community for in-depth discussion of books, posts that are better suited for [email protected] will be removed.

The hexbear rules against sectarian posts or comments will be strictly enforced here.

founded 1 year ago
MODERATORS